A Free-Market Energy Blog

Unilateral or Worldwide, Waxman-Markey Fails Standard Cost/Benefit Tests (CO2 “leakage” makes bad even worse)

By Robert Murphy -- May 26, 2009

Jim Manzi has a very good post introducing the analysis of costs and benefits of Waxman-Markey. Here I want to follow up on Manzi’s great start, by showing that Chip Knappenberger’s estimate of the climate benefits of Waxman-Markey (W-M) actually erred on the side of optimism in its assumptions.

Specifically, Knappenberger very conservatively ignored the problem of “leakage”–he didn’t model the fact that unilateral U.S. carbon caps would actually increase the rate at which other countries’ own emissions grow. What’s worse, even if the entire world signed on to the aggressive emission schedule in W-M, the resulting environmental benefits would be achieved at a staggering cost in terms of lost economic output.

No matter how you slice it–whether the U.S. goes it alone, or the rest of the world signs on too–the environmental benefits of W-M are swamped by its economic costs.

“Leakage”–An Important Variable. In a MasterResource post that has become a touchstone of the great climate debate, Chip Knappenberger used a standard model to assess the expected reductions in global mean temperatures if the U.S. faithfully adhered to the emission targets in W-M. Knappenberger found that by 2100, the projected global warming under two different “baseline” emission scenarios would be postponed by a handful of years.

The pro-interventionist scientists at RealClimate have conceded the basic validity of Chip’s analysis; they simply accuse him of rigging the game by considering unilateral U.S. action.

What is interesting is that Chip did not assume that the emissions of the rest of the world would grow more quickly because of (the stipulated) unilateral U.S. committment to W-M. Yet this would surely happen, because of a phenomenon referred to in the climate economics literature as leakage. The intuition is quite simple: If the U.S. imposes a steep price on operations that emit carbon, then U.S. industries will produce fewer carbon-intensive goods and services. (That’s the whole point, after all.)

Yet because of the reduction in output of these sectors, the world price of these items will tend to rise, which in turn will call forth greater output from (carbon-intensive) sectors in the unregulated countries.

I caution readers that some cynics of government action to limit climate change draw an unwarranted conclusion from this type of analysis. I have heard such critics say things like, “This is ridiculous! If the U.S. goes it alone, all we’ll do is ship all of our jobs to China, and we won’t affect global emissions one iota.”

Strictly speaking, that is taking it too far. For various reasons, it is not true that every cutback in carbon-intensive production in the U.S. would be perfectly offset by expanded production in an unregulated jurisdiction. However, even though there won’t be a one-for-one offset in terms of final goods produced, the relative carbon emissions is a different matter. This is because Chinese manufacturing operations emit more tons of carbon than American factories do, in order to produce the same physical amount of goods.

Hence, the amount of “leakage” resulting from a unilateral U.S. emissions cap is ultimately an empirical matter, but it would probably be very significant. To repeat, Chip’s analysis (described above) did not take this effect into account. Chip merely took two standard IPCC baseline emission scenarios, and then altered them by reducing the baseline growth in U.S. emissions in order to comply with the targets in W-M. He is consequently overestimating the environmental benefits of unilateral American adherence to the emission targets in W-M. In other words, the dotted lines in the chart above would be even closer to the solid lines, once the model took into account the superior profitability of Chinese carbon-intensive operations after the U.S. government hobbled American operations.

Leakage in the Context of the “Social Cost of Carbon.” Some of the more sophisticated critics of Chip’s analysis asked a reasonable question: Since plenty of economic models show a “social cost of carbon” emissions, it doesn’t really matter what the rest of the world does, right? After all, if emitting an extra ton of carbon today, translates into a (present discounted value of) an expected increase in future climate change damages of (say) $35, then it surely moves us in the direction of efficiency if the U.S. government slaps a penalty on domestic emitters, right?

There are two problems here. First, nobody is defending Waxman-Markey on the basis of cost/benefit analysis, because it can’t be done. There is a bit of a problem in comparing apples with apples (since the integrated assessment models gauging the impact of mitigation policies all assume concerted worldwide action), but it is safe to say that the emissions targets in W-M are far too aggressive, if we are going to be guided by the “social cost of carbon.”

For example, Table 3.10 (page 229) of Working Group III’s contribution to the IPCC Fourth Assessment Report (.pdf) shows that of 177 scenarios surveyed from the peer-reviewed literature, only 6 scenarios assumed worldwide emissions reductions in the steepest category of 50% – 85% by the year 2050. (Recall that W-M imposes a reduction of 83% by 2050. But note that the IPCC reductions are relative to 2000 emissions, while W-M’s 83% target is relative to 2005 emissions.)

If we turn to the specific DICE model by William Nordhaus–who is a pioneer and leader in this field, and who is a definite proponent of a carbon tax–we see that the aggressive emission cutbacks in W-M fail his cost/benefit test by a wide mark. The IPCC’s Table 3.10 and Nordhaus’s own results agree that capping emissions in 2050 at 83% below current levels, would correspond to Nordhaus’s estimates of a policy of capping atmospheric concentrations at no more than 1.5x preindustrial levels. (See Nordhaus’s Table 5-5, p. 96 here [.pdf]. Note that we are being conservative with our choice, because the steep emission cuts in W-M are arguably closer to the “Gore proposal,” which the DICE model finds even more destructive than the policy that we have instead chosen as a surrogate for W-M.)

Yet according to Nordhaus’s DICE model, such an aggressive policy would do far more harm to the economy, than it would yield in benefits of averted climate damage. Specifically, Nordhaus estimates that the policy corresponding to W-M targets would make the world some $15 trillion poorer relative to the business-as-usual baseline of no controls (see Table 5-1, page 82, here [.pdf]). Yes, worldwide commitment to the aggressive emission schedule in W-M would avert climate damages that would otherwise occur, which DICE values as a benefit of $12.6 trillion. But the draconian emission caps would require $27.24 trillion in abatement (compliance) costs. Thus the environmental benefits are swamped by the economic costs.

So we see that using the standard “social costs of carbon” approach, reveals that W-M imposes far too high a price on carbon emissions than is warranted by this Pigovian framework. That is why proponents of steep emission cuts must abandon standard cost/benefit analysis, and instead recommend particular environmental targets (such as stabilizing atmospheric concentrations at a presumed “safe” level) and then try to find the least-cost method of attaining them.

As a final point, we should note how the problem of leakage also influences the “social cost of carbon” as computed in various models. When Nordhaus or other economists calculate the social cost of carbon (SCC), they are asking what happens to the present discounted value of future environmental damages, if someone emits an additional ton of carbon today, while holding the assumed trajectory of all future emissions constant.

Now we see the weakness in this metric, when trying to assess the net benefits of unilateral climate policy. Once we take leakage into account, we see that the standard measure of SCC overstates (possibly grossly so) the true costs to society from an additional unit of emissions. In reality, there are two things going on: When a U.S. manufacturer produces more units of a carbon-intensive good, it is true that he emits more carbon dioxide into the atmosphere. This is what the SCC looks at, and judges him accordingly.

However, the U.S. manufacturer also pushes down the world price of the good in question, and that tends to cause other producers to emit less CO2. Thus, there is a positive externality laid on top of the negative externality. The greater the scope for leakage, the greater the positive externality. In the extreme, where U.S. operations would be completely outsourced to China (in terms of carbon emissions, if not output of final goods), then the correctly measured “social cost of carbon” for U.S. operations would be zero, in the context of a unilateral U.S. cap.

Conclusion. Here are the takeaway messages:

(A) If the U.S. implements Waxman-Markey unilaterally, the environmental benefits will be even less than indicated by Chip Knappenberger’s pessimistic analysis.

(B) If the whole world implements Waxman-Markey, then the loss to economic output will far exceed the reduction in expected environmental damages.

No matter how you slice it, Waxman-Markey fails standard cost/benefit tests. W-M advocates are certainly free to criticize standard cost/benefit tests, but they can’t stop there. They still need to justify quantitatively the steep emission targets in W-M. And to the extent that they invoke U.S. leadership in prodding the rest of the world to follow suit, proponents also need to come up with a plausible story showing the likelihood of worldwide action, with and without Waxman-Markey, versus some other possible U.S. approach.

Yet W-M proponents have done none of these things. Surely they could at least try–even in an informal blog post–to formalize their case, before expecting the American people to sign on to a plan that could cost trillions of dollars in forfeited economic growth, and which on its face will do very little to alter the course of global warming.

UPDATE 5/27: The analysis above takes the Waxman-Markey emissions reduction target of 83% (by 2050) at face value. In fact–as this CRA analysis [.pdf] explains on the bottom of pages 2 and 8–the current version of Waxman-Markey allows U.S. emitters to purchase international offsets to satisfy (some) of their compliance requirements. Having this option naturally reduces the abatement costs for any one country to meet the W-M targets. However, it is difficult to know what impact this subtlety has on the various IPCC models’ estimates of the cost of reducing worldwide emissions by 83% by 2050, because it is unclear how the availability of international offsets would scale upwards in the scenario where “the whole world implements Waxman-Markey.” To the extent that one country uses international offsets to pay another to achieve actual reductions in emissions, then these cost savings would presumably already be contained in at least most of the models studied by the IPCC, which typically assume least-cost implementation schemes. But to the extent that Waxman-Markey allows domestic emitters to, say, pay to avoid foreign deforestation, the “83% emissions cut by 2050” might be overestimating the abatement cost as reported by some of the IPCC models, if they are assuming reductions in actual emissions to reach stated targets.

13 Comments


  1. John Droz  

    Robert:

    Good job in your W-M analyses.

    As you know, a trump card that W-M supporters frequently pull out, is the fact that the US has high CO2 emissions per capita.

    Paraphrasing TT, what is missing is the fact that the US (until recently) enjoyed what can best be summarized as a “free market” and has one of, if not the most, carbon EFFICIENT (productive) economies in the world as measured by tons/$GDP [e.g. see EIA data: “www.eia.doe.gov/oiaf/1605/flash/flash.html”].

    We’re often accused of representing less than 5% world population but 25%± of GHG emissions — yet we SELDOM hear the other fact that we’re responsible for 30%+ of world GDP and an even larger proportion (35%±) of the world’s food. We feed, clothe, house and protect the world which (in effect) is now being turned against us to try to make us feel guilty.

    Other evidence of our efficiency (and already reasonable efforts) is to look at US CO2 over the last 60 years. Despite massive increase in transportation mileage, electricity generation, concrete usage, etc., our CO2 emissions have gone up relatively little.

    Additionally I see few assessing the negative global impact attributable to our wearing a hair shirt and voluntarily (and unilaterally) handicapping our economy. You have touched on some of that in this piece (thank you), but (IMO) more should be done.

    For instance, start with a comprehensive list of ALL of the benefits the US provides the rest of the planet. Then analyze the global costs for when these will be cut back.

    Let’s keep things in perspective.

    Reply

  2. Andrew  

    NOW I understand why they are trying to say “It’s even worse than we thought”…

    Reply

  3. Houston Chronicle: Climate Alarmism and Policy Activism, but no Economic Analysis — MasterResource  

    […] substantial costs, have not been refuted. Pending further review, in fact, Waxman-Markey badly flunks conventional economic cost/benefit […]

    Reply

  4. C3H Editor  

    I have found this series of postings very helpful and will be re-reading this particular one again to get my arms around.

    One quibble that I have is following comment: “Yes, worldwide commitment to the aggressive emission schedule in W-M would avert climate damages that would otherwise occur….” If Chip’s world impact analysis is correct, then o.5 C increase will be avoided (probably less, since Chip assumed a perfect implementation). I’m curious as to what “climate damages” will be averted by an aggressive global W-M policy, if temperature avoidance amounts to only 0.5 C.

    I actually think this is an important clarification that is needed for all policy makers. If facts (actual climate damage averted) can’t support your statement, then it just muddies the water and the debate.

    Reply

  5. Tom Jefferson  

    One question, who is going to feed the world after the USA industry is shut down?

    Basic? No?

    Reply

  6. We won’t solve global warming through voluntary effort – Kevin Burke  

    […] usual result is overpayment for little actual […]

    Reply

  7. Cost/Benefit Analysis Cannot Justify Waxman-Markey’s Aggressive Targets — MasterResource  

    […] explained this point in a previous post, but since then Resources for the Future (RFF) has released an excellent primer on climate […]

    Reply

  8. Another Look at the Costs/Benefits of Waxman-Markey: A Dog that Won’t Hunt — MasterResource  

    […] an earlier post, I tried to show that this view is simply false. According to the Intergovernmental Panel on […]

    Reply

  9. "Green" China: Big PR vs. King Coal (move over dung, primitive biomass, and Waxman-Markey) — MasterResource  

    […] symbolic measures. Indeed, U.S. industry would move to China to transfer emissions (called “leakage“) under a stringent U.S. carbon-dioxide […]

    Reply

  10. Trading Eights » One Controversial, Uncertain, Imperfect Chance: Is It Worth It?  

    […] say Bravo! to the few pundits, like Jim Manzi and Robert Murphy, who have tried to use respected economic models to perform a cost-benefit analysis of […]

    Reply

  11. Climate Economics 101 & Policy Activism — MasterResource  

    […] conclusion, I refer readers to my earlier post on the cost/benefit calculations of Waxman-Markey, showing that its advocates have not demonstrated […]

    Reply

  12. China Goes ‘Green’ – Collecting the Pot at the Climate Policy Poker Table — MasterResource  

    […] without the wholesale transfer of US manufacturing industry to China, (called “leakage“) under a stringent U.S. carbon-dioxide régime, the putative positive climate impacts of such […]

    Reply

  13. We won’t solve global warming through voluntary effort | Kevin Burke  

    […] gasoline? The whole point of market prices is to do these calculations for us.The usual result is overpayment for little actual benefit.3) When the laws are set up so that the cost of pollution is low, it […]

    Reply

Leave a Reply